注册 | 登录
  • 首  页
    |
  • 关于学会
    |
  • 网上入会
    |
  • 学术年会
    |
  • 学会论文
    |
  • 学会课题
    |
  • 学会报告
    |
  • 学会活动
    |
  • 产学研基地
    |
  • 特约研究员
    |
  • 资料中心
    |
学会介绍 学会章程 会员管理服务及收费办法 组织机构 学会领导 专家委员会 学会年度工作计划 学会文件 联系方式
入会须知 注册会员 理事申请表下载 会费标准及缴纳方式
关于年会 历届年会回顾 最新年会动态 最新学术年会征文 历届获奖名单 特约评委申报 关于分论坛 分论坛申请 历届分论坛
征文通知 征文提交 物流经济 物流管理 物流技术与工程 采购 供应链管理 英文文献
课题介绍 课题通知 课题计划 历年获奖课题 课题申报 课题结题 课题申报书下载 课题延期申请表下载 研究报告格式规范下载 结题报告模板下载
关于报告 中国物流发展报告 中国物流重点课题报告 中国物流学术前沿报告 中国物流园区发展报告 中国冷链物流发展报告 生产资料流通发展报告 中国采购发展报告
中国物流发展报告会 全国物流园区工作年会 物流企业财税与投融资工作会 产学研结合工作会 中国物流学术年会 日日顺创客训练营
管理办法 产学研基地动态 申请表下载 申请表提交 基地复核 产学研会议信息
管理办法 申请流程 聘任条件 申请表下载 特约研究员相关文件
学会工作动态 物流政策及评论 学术年会论文 学术年会资料 学会报告 会员通讯 领导讲话 学会文件 学会课题 其他
  • 2005年
  • 2006年
  • 2007年
  • 2008年
  • 2009年
  • 2010年
  • 2011年
  • 2012年
  • 2013年
  • 2014年
  • 2015年
  • 2016年
  • 2017年
  • 2018年
  • 2019年
  • 2020年
  • 2021年
当前位置:首页 > 资料中心 > 学术年会论文 > 英文文献 > 2015年
Risk Mitigation Benefit From Backup Suppliers in thePresence of the Horizontal Fairness Concern
来源: 时间:2015/12/21 10:23:20 作者:
  

Risk Mitigation Benefit From Backup Suppliers in thePresence of the Horizontal Fairness Concern *

 

ABSTRACT

The backup supply strategy is demonstrated as an effective approach to mitigating supply risk. We study a supply chain in which a leader manufacturer designs a contract to a potential backup supplier to mitigate the yield uncertainty of the primary supplier. In this context, the backup supplier may compare with the primary supplier and have horizontal fairness concerns. We model the contract design problem using a Stackelberg game and characterize the optimal decisions for the manufacturer and backup supplier, in both fairness and off-fairness settings. The theoretical results show that the leader manufacturer must sacrifice his own payoff to balance the payoffs of both suppliers. As a result, using a self-interested backup supplier is the dominating strategy, whereas using a fair-minded backup supplier is only suggested when the reliability of the primary supplier is low and the fairness concern of the backup supplier is not strong. Additionally, the backup supplier only benefits from fairness concerns when the level is not exceeding a threshold value. With regard to high fairness levels beyond this threshold, fairness concern has negative effects on the monetary payoff and even might lead to loss of the business. By conducting laboratory experiments, we provide evidence of the horizontal fairness concern from the backup supplier. Further, we show that if the primary supplier also has horizontal fairness concerns, the leader manufacturer can conditionally benefit from a promoted yield reliability due to an extra effort from the primary supplier.

Subject Areas: supply chain management, option contract, supply risk, and fairness concern.

 

INTRODUCTION
Backup suppliers are widely employed in industries, such as the aircraft (Chen, Zhao, & Zhou, 

2012), pharmaceutical (Chopra, 2007), and electronics (Tomlin, 2006) industries. One contracting strategy is to compensate for backup deliveries with capacity reservations, as is practiced in the following example. Toyota procures P-valves from a low-price, high-volume primary supplier, Aisin Seiki Co., and reserves in advance some capacity from a secondary flexible backup supplier, such as Somic, to protect the supply stream against possible disruptions (Sheffi, 2007).

In a setting with a manufacturer and a primary supplier plus a backup supplier, the manufacturer (he) has an established contract with a low-price primary supplier for regular supply, who is subject to yield uncertainty, and then develops an alternative contract with a reliable but expensive backup supplier (she) for contingent deliveries. Being conscious about the contingent rerouting option, the backup supplier may consider her relative payoff compared with that of the primary supplier when making decisions, which influences her behavior. As such, the manufacturer’s ability to obtain a contingent supply is uncertain because the backup supplier may not be willing to do business with him due to unfair treatment. For that reason, we are motivated to study the mitigation strategy for a manufacturer to avoid mitigating failure because of the possible fairness concern of his backup supplier by analyzing how he should contract with his backup supplier to ensure a responsive supply and, at the same time, benefit from contingent sourcing.

Real-world examples in which fairness concerns are important abound. In the Japanese automotive supply chain, automakers, notably Toyota, rely heavily on fair transaction relationships with their suppliers. As a result, suppliers are more likely to trust Japanese automakers to treat them fairly (Dyer, 1997). Another example occurred between two Chinese firms, Gome (one of the top three home appliance retailers) and Gree (the leading air conditioner manufacturer in China) in summer 2004. Gree decided to withdraw all of its products from Gome stores despite a significant loss in market share because Gree felt that Gome’s demand of additional summer promotion fees was unfair (AsiaInfo Services, 2004; Liu, Huang, Luo, &Zhao, 2012). Additionally, in 2008, Lego Group rejected Walmart Canada’s demand of price reduction to maintain a fair pricing structure in the Canadian and U.S. markets. Such rejection ended the business relationship between Lego Group and Walmart Canada (Georgiades, 2008).

Although the above anecdotes clearly illustrate the important role of fairness in firm performance, research on fairness in supply chain management has only recently attracted attention. Extant studies have shown that supply chain parties with fairness concerns make decisions deviating from the predictions provided by self-interested profit-maximization models (e.g., Loch & Wu, 2008; Cui, Raju, & Zhang, 2007; Demirag, Chen, & Li, 2010; Fehr, Klein, & Schmidt, 2007; Wu 2013; Katok, Olsen, & Pavlov, 2012; Katok & Pavlov 2013). In particular, in contract designs, a constant wholesale price can coordinate a dyadic channel when channel members are concerned about fairness (Cui et al., 2007; Demirag et al., 2010). Coordinating contracts result in inequivalent supply chain performance, although they are mathematically equivalent (Wu, 2013). The inequality-aversion model can describe the contract choice predictions rather accurately (Fehr et al., 2007). Katok, Olsen, and Pavlov (2012) consider fairness concern as the private information of supply chain partners and show that a wholesale pricing can conditionally coordinate the supply chain, despite the asymmetric information. Katok and Pavlov (2013) investigate the major factor contributing to rejections in supply chain contracts, and report that inequality aversion has the most explanatory power regarding retailers’ behavior compared to bounded rationality, and incomplete information. All these studies typically investigate dyadic settings with the fairness concern on the vertical dimension between seller and buyer.

While fairness in dyadic supplier-buyer relationships is important, triadic settings formed by one seller/buyer and two buyers/sellers are also common in practice, where horizontal fairness concerns may be induced between peers. Fairness concerns in horizontal dimensions provide a meaningful frame of reference for identifying individual firms that participate in the formation and execution of supply chain transactions. Because these participants engage in social exchanges and derive complex perceptions, an examination of horizontal fairness concern in a triadic supply chain is essential for generating additional insights on effective supply chain management.

需要[2]积分

阅读全文

关于我们 | 媒体互动 | 站点留言 | 友情链接 | 在线投稿 | 网站地图

地 址: 北京市丰台区丽泽路16号院2号楼铭丰大厦1601(100073) 电 话:010-83775681 E-mail:CSL56@vip.163.com
Copyright 2000-2019 in 中国物流与采购联合会、中国物流学会版权所有 技术支持:中国物流与采购联合会网络事业部
中国物流与采购网:京ICP备05024070号 中国物流联盟网:京ICP备05037064号